[Published in the ASA section newsletter Altruism, Morality, and Social Solidarity Forum, 4 (1): 25-26 in 2013.]
Graeber,
David. 2011. Debt: The
First 5,000 Years. New
York: Melville House Press.
Typically,
“debt” is only viewed as an economic phenomenon, with very simple
rules and principles: when someone owes another person something,
then this debt is as official and non-negotiable as a contract. David
Graeber dismantles this myopic conceptualization of debt via an
expansive analysis of many millennia of human history. He finds that
“debt” is not as simple or clear as most people assume. The most
immediate observation readers will be struck by is that the etymology
of many words are linked to the social concept of debt, including:
honor, sin, guilt, forgiveness, reckoning, redemption, freedom,
credit, and interest. It is helpful to know that the background of
these words derive from centuries-old debates about debt or that
their histories intersected with debt debates at some point in time.
According
to Graeber, “debt” is a social obligation we hold to each other.
Although debt is often considered only in monetary terms (“How much
money do we owe someone for that product or service?”), it is much
broader, and refers to all the ways in which we find ourselves
obligated to each other (economically or otherwise). Since debt is
ultimately about our social relationships, debt is therefore a social
construction. The answer to the question “What do we actually owe
to each other?” is never quite certain, since debt is
socially-arbitrated and can, thus, be re-negotiated. Graeber goes to
great lengths to demonstrate—philosophically as well as through
copious anthropological evidence—that most people actually want
to be in debt to each other. People enjoy doing things for each
other, both feeling gracious for giving (and thus incurring other
debt) as well as receiving gifts from each other (and landing in each
other’s debt). Even though free-market economic theory pretends
humans do not like this, the truth is that most of us actually seek
out debt, because we enjoy the social relationships that come with
exchange.
Much
of Graeber’s Debt
is focused on the oscillations between credit and money, which define
general periods in human history over the last five-thousand years.
Despite the popular assumption that pre-money economies operated on
principles of barter (two parties exchanging things of equal value or
desire), Graeber argues this is an unsubstantiated myth and that no
society has ever been discovered which has operated strictly on the
basis of barter. The reasons are self-evident, according to Graeber:
squaring and settling one's debts indicates a lack of desire to
continue associating with others (“Okay, we both have what we want,
so this transaction and our relationship is completed”). Thus, if
direct, bartered exchange happens it usually indicates that the
people involved lacked faith
in each other or are strangers,
and they do not expect or wish to see the other person again. In
other words, an “even trade” often indicates a lack of trust or
that we are unsure of our ability to get what we are owed from that
person in the future. Consequently, it is also usually uncouth, even
offensive, to keep track of what friends and neighbors owe each
other. This is clear in close, intimate relationships: friends or
lovers who always demand an immediate, equal trade of kindness,
pleasantries, or favors—and who keep track of any debt the other
party has—are likely to be characterized as pathological.
Another
reason why no economy has ever been based wholly upon barter is that
it is generally impractical: what are the chances that two people
have exactly what each other need? Instead, a loose system of
“credit” is more practical; we approximate our general
indebtedness to each other (at least in less-intimate relations) and
we know that we can rely on the other party to help out when there is
the need. A system of credit (accounting either goods or services)
also mandates that we stay in each other’s debt, thereby ensuring
constant interaction and sociality. This is one of Graeber’s most
compelling arguments: human sociability (and, even solidarity) is
premised on debt (i.e. social obligation).
Graeber
dedicates a sizable portion of Debt
to discussing the epochal fluctuations between credit and money,
starting during the early Agrarian period, then the Axial age
(sometimes called the classic age), the medieval era, the industrial
age, and finally the period following Nixon's decision in 1971 to
detach the US from the gold-standard. During each period, the general
human relationship to debt changed. Graeber argues that money,
slavery, markets, and states arise alongside each other during the
Axial age, in what he calls the military-coinage-slavery complex.
Most of these phenomena disappear during the medieval period, shrink,
or go into latency. Yet, the industrial age rekindles them again. For
example, slavery (by definition, the consequence of a debt that
cannot be paid back) makes a comeback and war begins, once again, to
predominate relations between large, centralizing states, all of whom
resume the use of coin money.
The
present-day political ramifications of Debt
could scarcely be clearer: debt is not only important to economies
but is also fundamental to human relationships. To eliminate all
debt—such as what Right-wing forces seek for the US federal
government (as in the 2011 “debt ceiling” debate in the
Congress)—is not merely preposterous, but would represent a
deathblow to social relations. Contrary to popularly-incanted
mantras, debt is not universally bad, nor is it something to avoid at
all costs. A deeper question emerges for Graeber: why do we “have
to” pay back our loans, especially for those debts that are created
by unethical, hierarchical practices (e.g. International Monetary
Fund-created debt for poor countries, decade-long crippling student
loans, or predatory home loans that end in foreclosure)? Those who
hold monetary debt over people tend to be wealthy and powerful people
(i.e. affiliated with banks, landlords, loan-sharks, credit card
companies), and, let's face it, they can handle losing the obligation
that the poor “owe” them, which creates non-free relations more
akin to slavery than mutual aid.
Graeber's
suggested solution to the enslaving characteristics of some debt and
the socially constructed qualities that make it negotiable, is
proposed at the end of Debt:
he calls for a Biblical-style “Jubilee” to wipe-free the slate on
these arduous forms of debt existing between unequal parties. Jubilee
was a commonplace practice in many earlier periods of human
history—in fact, it was regularly done, not only for purposes of
social justice, but also to re-balance societies that were on the
brink of revolution. The latter is likely the very thing that
motivated the Saudi Arabian monarchy when it wiped-out some forms of
consumer debt for its citizens, gave government employees pay raises,
and offered cheap, subsidized loans—all in the wake of the Arab
Spring. Autocratic regimes watched with fear as the Egyptian
dictatorship was overthrown; so, instead of letting the burdens of
debt become so extreme that they threaten the monarchy's hold over
its citizens, the Saudi Arabian government deemed it smarter for the
oil-wealth coffers to be used to soften the worst injustices of
capitalism. Jubilee could help eliminate un-payable debt and thus
return us to the socially-useful sort of debt that obliges us to keep
working together in social communities (what Graeber simply
identifies as “communism”).
While
there is an abundance of wisdom to admire with Debt,
Graeber's incredibly-fine attention to detail sometimes distracts
from the general argument. Also, although his prose is fascinating,
Graeber has the odd habit of starting nearly every single paragraph
via direct, yet non-obvious reference to the prior paragraph (e.g.
writing “this” without indicating exactly what previous thing he
is referring to). Thus, putting down and picking-up the book makes
for a discordant experience. Yet, such minor aesthetic concerns
aside, Debt
is not only timely and consciousness-expanding, but also an
entertaining read. Students of solidarity, altruism, mutual aid, and
human relations generally would benefit greatly from Debt’s
insights.
No comments:
Post a Comment